Warning: fopen(/home/virtual/epih/journal/upload/ip_log/ip_log_2024-03.txt): failed to open stream: Permission denied in /home/virtual/lib/view_data.php on line 83 Warning: fwrite() expects parameter 1 to be resource, boolean given in /home/virtual/lib/view_data.php on line 84 Authors’ Reply: Vaccination, payment, and COVID-19
Skip Navigation
Skip to contents

Epidemiol Health : Epidemiology and Health

OPEN ACCESS
SEARCH
Search

Articles

Page Path
HOME > Epidemiol Health > Volume 43; 2021 > Article
COVID-19: Correspondence
Authors’ Reply: Vaccination, payment, and COVID-19
Jelena Dotlic1orcid, Vida Jeremic Stojkovic1orcid, Paul Cummins2orcid, Marija Milic3orcid, Tatjana Gazibara1orcid
Epidemiol Health 2021;43:e2021100.
DOI: https://doi.org/10.4178/epih.e2021100
Published online: November 23, 2021

1Institute of Epidemiology, Faculty of Medicine, University of Belgrade, Belgrade, Serbia

2Department of Medical Education, Icahn School of Medicine at Mount Sinai, New York, NY, USA

3Faculty of Medicine, University of Pristina temporarily settled in Kosovska Mitrovica, Kosovska Mitrovica, Serbia

Correspondence: Tatjana Gazibara Institute of Epidemiology, Faculty of Medicine, University of Belgrade, 26A Visegradska, Belgrade 11000, Serbia E-mail: tatjanagazibara@yahoo.com

©2021, Korean Society of Epidemiology

This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

  • 6,399 Views
  • 110 Download
Dear Editor,
We read Choi’s letter with great interest [1]. However, we are compelled to respond to the criticisms in it.
First, we structured our initial comment as a response to a publication [2] that debated whether the Serbian government is paying its citizens to receive the coronavirus disease 2019 (COVID-19) vaccine. Our point was to explain that it is a mistake to characterize the actions of the Serbian government as payments as opposed to financial relief [3]. While perceptions of financial incentives can depend on numerous factors, including the manner in which they are offered [4,5], if they are not payments, then the ethical questions about paying for vaccination should be set aside. These cash transfers are either payments or financial relief; people’s perceptions of them cannot change that.
This first objection does not respond to our claim that these are not payments. Moreover, the amount of 25 euros (or any amount whatsoever) would not likely distort the perceptions of a person who categorically objects to vaccination. Moreover, this specific amount of financial relief would not materially change one’s socioeconomic status in Serbia, which is classified as an upper-middle-income country according to the World Bank categorization of worlds’ economies. Fears of post-vaccination adverse effects and potential harm can be balanced by evidence-based data, and it is not likely that this fear would be easily eliminated by offering (any amount) of money. However, it could be the “final push” for people who were hesitant and uncertain about vaccination and contribute to a change in their point of view by motivating them to seek additional information and ultimately accept vaccination. One could argue that financial incentives are a less intrusive option for increasing vaccination coverage than alternatives like punishment and movement restrictions. This is consistent with the public health consensus that the least intrusive means should be used to achieve public health goals.
Second, we reject the characterization of our explanation as a straw man fallacy because we are not attributing an artificially weak argument to people. Instead, we are objecting to the use of a term that has specific connotations related to research ethics in the context of discussing a public health ethics question. The passage cited from Jecker [4] conflates undue influence (i.e., offering excessive and unjustifiable reward to secure compliance) and coercion (i.e., convincing a person to act contrary to his or her free will through force or threats). However, to call cash transfer incentives for vaccination coercive is inaccurate given the definition of coercion. The recent public health measures in Austria, involving lockdown for non-vaccinated people [6], do represent, in fact, a genuine case of coercion. To claim that something is coercive because it feels coercive (and how is that established?) is to commit the same mistake as made in objection 1.
Third, we agree that assessing the appropriateness of a measure relative to the situation is necessary. All measures to increase vaccination coverage stemmed from the efforts to achieve optimum herd immunity as soon as possible. Therefore, financial incentives are offered as a form of a one-time reward to those who contribute to the protection of the health of the population and help to advance and develop the community. However, we do not agree that financial incentives for vaccination conflict with the necessity to identify reasons for vaccine hesitancy. The appropriateness of immunization as public health strategy has never been considered problematic. Whether or not immunization should be compulsory is indeed a matter of ethical assessment. Nevertheless, financial incentives are not part of that debate.
The main goal of research about people’s reasons underlying vaccine hesitancy is to adjust public health campaigns to address those concerns and persuade them to eventually receive the vaccine. In the meantime, given that such research may take some time to complete, public health authorities should put all their efforts into increasing vaccination rates, while balancing the value of respect for individual autonomy. Financial incentives are just one of many public health measures. Although data in the literature showed that financial incentives could indeed increase the vaccination rate [7], the long-term effects of financial and all other measures on increasing vaccine acceptance remain unclear and insufficiently explored.
Finally, we agree that a short essay is insufficient to discuss such a complex topic. The word limit, typical of medical journals, compelled us to articulate our reasoning in a concise manner. We plan to elaborate our analysis for future publications.

CONFLICT OF INTEREST

The authors have no conflicts of interest to declare for this study.

AUTHOR CONTRIBUTIONS

Conceptualization: JD, VJS, PC, MM, TG. Data curation: JD, VJS, PC, MM, TG. Formal analysis: JD, VJS, PC, MM, TG. Methodology: JD, VJS, PC, MM, TG. Visualization: JD, VJS, PC, MM, TG. Writing – original draft: JD, TG. Writing – review & editing: VJS, PC, MM.

  • 1. Choi YJ. Letter to the editor: enhancing COVID-19 vaccination coverage using financial incentives: arguments to help health providers counterbalance erroneous claims. Epidemiol Health 2021;43:e2021087.ArticlePubMedPMC
  • 2. Holt E. Serbia begins paying citizens to receive a COVID-19 vaccine. Lancet 2021;397:1793.ArticlePubMedPMC
  • 3. Dotlic J, Jeremic Stojkovic V, Cummins P, Milic M, Gazibara T. Enhancing COVID-19 vaccination coverage using financial incentives: arguments to help health providers counterbalance erroneous claims. Epidemiol Health 2021;43:e2021081.ArticlePubMedPMC
  • 4. Thaler RH. Misbehaving: the making of behavioral economics. New York: W.W. Norton & Company; 2015. p 55-84.
  • 5. Kim HB. Letter to the editor: financial incentives for COVID-19 vaccination. Epidemiol Health 2021;43:e2021088.ArticlePubMedPMC
  • 6. Austria orders lockdown for unvaccinated amid Covid surge. NBC News. 2021 Nov 16 [cited 2021 Nov 20]. Available from: https://www.nbcnews.com/news/world/austria-orders-lockdown-unvaccinated-covid-surge-rcna5598.
  • 7. Campos-Mercade P, Meier AN, Schneider FH, Meier S, Pope D, Wengström E. Monetary incentives increase COVID-19 vaccinations. Science 2021;374:879-882.ArticlePubMed

Figure & Data

References

    Citations

    Citations to this article as recorded by  


      Epidemiol Health : Epidemiology and Health